Introduction
briefings
about
learn more
Introduction
briefings
about
learn more
Introduction
briefings
about
learn more

Restrict Non-Competes for Productivity and Prosperity

Restrict Non-Competes for Productivity and Prosperity

Some economic data suggests non-compete covenants harm productivity, innovation, entrepreneurship, wages, and public interest. The UK should launch a review on non-competes and their impact on the labour market.

Authors

David Cabrelli, Alan Eustace

Date

August 9, 2024

August 9, 2024

Share

Copy Link

Restrict Non-Competes for Productivity and Prosperity

04-04-23
ukdayone - - - blog
©2024

Some economic data suggests non-compete covenants harm productivity, innovation, entrepreneurship, wages, and public interest. The UK should launch a review on non-competes and their impact on the labour market.

Authors

David Cabrelli, Alan Eustace

Share

Copy Link

Date

August 9, 2024

Summary

  • The UK Government should stop the abuse of non-compete covenants in employment contracts, and appoint an Expert Working Group to research the problem, design the appropriate regulatory solution, and identify reforms to the existing rules governing the enforceability of non-compete covenants, in line with Government priorities.

  • There are three distinct policy objectives for tighter regulation of non-compete covenants: the economic efficiency objective; the fairness objective; and the (economic) freedom objective.

  • The abuse of non-compete covenants is bad for economic productivity and innovation, entrepreneurship, wages and worker power, and the public interest. Although the UK courts already restrict non-compete covenants, many are ruled to be enforceable, as existing legal tests do not adequately account for these policy goals.

  • There is a range of options for further regulation, each of which correlates in some measure to these policy rationales:

    • Ban after a certain time period;

    • Ban above (or below) a certain income level; 

    • Mandatory compensation

    • Industry-specific regulations;

    • Reform of existing common law tests.

  • The previous UK Government undertook to legislate to introduce a ban after a certain time period, but the policy was underdeveloped and never implemented. Other jurisdictions like the USA have already acted to curtail non-compete covenants.

The Challenge and Opportunity

Main Problem and Challenges

The overall challenges of productivity stagnation in the UK economy, depressed real wages, and the disempowerment of working people across the country are well-documented. The specific challenge this paper addresses is the contribution made by non-compete covenants in employment contracts to this overall picture. In essence, such covenants exacerbate labour market concentration by placing frictions and costs on the ability of workers to move to a new employer or set up a competing business.

First, the evidence of productivity stagnation, depressed wages, and worker disempowerment:

Sources: Financial Times, The Productivity Institute

The decline in real wages broadly reflects the productivity data:

Sources: BBC, Financial Times

The consequences of this stagnation are that workers in this country are left £5,000 - £11,000 per annum worse off than they should be.

Worker power is, of course, harder to measure than real wages and even productivity. However, Eurofound has developed a variety of measures which give a fair picture of worker empowerment. The UK performs particularly poorly on ‘industrial democracy’, which includes worker participation in how businesses are run and how corporate decisions are made. Figure 5 compares the UK to selected peer countries and the average across the EU.

Source: Eurofound

In the UK, disaffected workers, paid no better than the previous generation, are stuck in unproductive ways of working, and with low productivity in the economy: a recipe for economic and wage stagnation and social discontent. The position is exacerbated by the decline in trade union membership over the past fifty years and the severe legal restrictions on trade union activity that have been well-documented elsewhere

This leaves unhappy workers with only one option: to exercise their right to labour mobility and leave their jobs. This is where non-compete covenants enter the picture and work to employers’ advantage.

Non-compete Covenants: Data and Existing Legal Regulation

As far back as the 15th century, we see established businesses trying to restrict the ability of their employees to move job to their rivals, or set up a new business in competition with their former employer, by means of terms of the employment contract. In recent decades, their use has spread from senior employees in highly specialised industries, throughout the economy, all around the world. In just the last few years, governments from the United States of America to Australia are making efforts to crack down on the abuse of these ‘non-compete covenants’. 

Non-compete covenants are express terms in employees’ contracts of employment which prohibit them from working for a business which competes with their employer after the termination of the employment contract. They vary in how widely a competitor is defined (for example, specific industries or areas of the country), and for how long the restriction is in place (six to twelve months is not uncommon). They are currently regulated in the UK by the common law and in any given case, it is left to the courts to determine whether they go no further than is reasonably necessary to protect an employer’s legitimate commercial interests, like trade secrets and  goodwill with clients.

There is evidence to suggest that widespread use of non-compete covenants hinders productivity and innovation, depresses wages and enables employers to extract excessive rents at the expense of workers. This is because they either disincentivise, restrict or prevent: 

  • more productive businesses from hiring experienced workers to grow output,

  • workers from leaving employment immediately to start a new business to compete with their employer, and

  • workers from shopping around for the highest wages on offer in an industry.

The most significant problem for further restricting regulating non-compete covenants in UK employment law is that we have very little data on how prevalent they are, nor on their effects across industries and the economy as a whole. Most studies on non-compete covenants are specific to the US labour market, and it is unclear whether either the prevalence or effects of non-compete covenants indicated by that research transfers to other economies. The limited research conducted to date on this aspect of the UK labour market is inconclusive, and to a certain extent contradictory: a 2022 survey commissioned by the (then-) Department of Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy on the prevalence of non-compete covenants indicated 19% of employees have a non-compete covenant in their contract of employment, and that such covenants are used by 52% of businesses for at least some of their workers; but in January 2024, a report by the UK Competitions and Market Authority (‘CMA’) claimed 26% of workers have non-compete covenants in their employment contracts (rising to 40% in the information and communication technologies and professional and scientific services sectors), but only 15% of businesses use them.

The second problem is that, as the Government’s 2022 Impact Assessment acknowledged, there is evidence pointing in both directions on the effect of non-competes on productivity and wage growth in the UK economy specifically. Even this mixed assessment in the CMA report is made on the basis of evidence which has been called into question. Although the balance of available evidence seems to favour some kind of ban, it does not compare the current equilibrium with one where different institutional arrangements may be available. 

As for worker power, non-competes self-evidently restrict the ‘exit’ option for workers to assert their interests and exercise their freedom of mobility, and thereby reduce the incentives for employers to take worker ‘voice’ seriously.  But, on the other hand, in principle, the ability to ‘lock in’ skilled workers may incentivise businesses to make long-term capital investments, and provide training to staff and pay higher wages. This may improve skills and make workers more productive. For example, the CMA report suggested that workers with non-compete covenants receive more formal training from their employers and that employers may be more likely ‘to share confidential client relationships with employees... [and that such] investment in general human capital and client relationships may make employees more productive and therefore increase their earnings’. The CMA also points to a number of factors which affect labour market competition, including concentration of firms in a geographic area or industry, making it hard to assess the effect of non-compete covenants specifically.

As such, we simply do not know which dynamics are at play in the UK economy as a whole, and in particular we do not know if the effects of non-compete covenants are different across sectors. The first opportunity, therefore, is to understand the UK labour market better by commissioning further, more targeted, research. It is certainly the case that the evidence from the US-based research relied on by the UK Government in 2022 is informative for the UK, given the institutional similarities between the two economies. But there are specifics to the present UK economic situation which urge caution. For example, we note below the approaches taken to the regulation of non-compete covenants in the US, Germany, France and Australia. Depending on how businesses respond to recent changes in the regulation of non-compete covenants elsewhere, a more permissive regime may allow the UK to attract investment from jurisdictions where they are banned, and banning them here may divert domestic or foreign investment to jurisdictions where they are allowed. With this in mind, rigorous econometric data is required on both the prevalence and effect of non-compete covenants in the UK labour market specifically. 

In the final analysis, we do not know what the legitimate ‘uses’ of non-compete covenants in the UK economy might be, and how much ‘abuse’ there is. If the costs associated with the latter outweigh the benefits related to the former, then we need regulation to curtail abuse of non-compete covenants: there is already research identifying an economic model as to how such a cost-benefit analysis would be best undertaken. This would involve recasting the UK’s approach to non-compete covenants and their place in the labour market, with their curtailed use improving productivity, efficiency and economic growth and increasing the earnings of workers. 

But we cannot know what works and why if we adopt a single regulatory response on the basis of existing evidence. If there is any value to non-competes in the form of higher investment in skills and training, it will be very difficult to measure this after a ban is imposed. A more targeted approach might allow us to mitigate some of the negative impacts while retaining some of the beneficial effects of these contractual relationships; that is why this paper offers the menu of options below.

Policy Rationales for Intervention and Reform and Menu of Options for Reform

There are three distinct policy objectives for tighter regulation of non-compete covenants: first, the economic efficiency objective; secondly, the fairness objective; and finally, the (economic) freedom objective. The economic efficiency case for reform is that restraining the employer’s use of non-compete clauses will enhance growth, boost productivity and investment in R&D and human capital and facilitate innovation and entrepreneurship, because talented workers will be able to immediately leave their employment to work for a competitor or set up their own competing business. Secondly, the fairness rationale provides that since non-compete covenants exacerbate labour market concentration and suppress wages and working conditions for workers, reform will boost wage levels and improve working conditions. Finally, reform to enhance the (economic) freedom of workers will ensure that workers are not unnecessarily restrained or prevented from plying their trade, deploying their skills and exercising their freedom of mobility.

Each of these rationales is clearly a valuable goal for the UK Government to pursue. But as flagged above, there are limits to how confident we can be that a one-size-fits-all regulatory response will accomplish them. For example, there may be costs to economic efficiency if a ban on non-compete covenants mean employers invest less in skills training for their workers. Likewise, wages could decrease if workers are left without those skills. In this, the comparison could be made with intellectual property protection: we know that allowing businesses to patent innovative technology reduces its adoption across the economy and stifles competition, but we pay this cost to incentivise more research and development. So the compromise is time-limited patent protection.

For the purposes of this paper, however, we should follow the balance of evidence and take the policy justifications at their height. Flowing from these three policy rationales, we have identified five alternative ways of regulating non-compete covenants, each with advantages and disadvantages relative to the variety of policy goals the regulation may pursue. Whichever of the five options in the menu for reform is or are selected is largely dependent on the priority accorded by policymakers to each of these three policy objectives relative to each other. 

In summary, the options are:

  • Ban after a certain time period;

  • Ban above (or below) a certain income level; 

  • Mandatory compensation

  • Industry-specific regulations;

  • Reform of existing common law tests.

The first option is a product of each of the economic efficiency, fairness and freedom rationales and would mirror the reforms proposed by the previous Conservative Government. Under this scheme, non-compete covenants would be treated as unenforceable if they exceeded a particular time period, e.g. three, six months, etc. 

The second possible reform involves an embargo on employers using non-competes above or below a particular salary threshold. Banning non-compete covenants for highly-paid workers would encourage mobility of the most productive and innovative workers, allowing start-ups to acquire experienced employees. Banning non-compete covenants below a salary threshold is consistent with both the fairness and (economic) freedom goals to the extent that workers without high-demand skills should never experience any limitations on their freedom to move jobs, whereas high-skilled staff who have the market power to bargain for themselves could agree to be ‘locked in’.

As for the third option, this envisages that employers must pay the worker for the benefit of the non-compete covenant, reflecting again the fairness rationale and the law in other European countries, eg Germany and France. 

The fourth reform is one which largely reflects the efficiency objective insofar as it tailors the strength of the restriction on the use of non-competes to the economic needs of the industry or market in which the employer is operating, with the potential for ongoing revision in line with changing conditions. 

The final option again is one that combines the efficiency, fairness and freedom rationales. It would enjoin the courts to strike down non-compete covenants where they are contrary to the public interest, ie that the courts take into account the economic power of the employer, and the extent to which the employer benefits from such power and the covenant imposes excessive social costs on the public if it were to be enforced. However, the weakness from the perspective of economic efficiency is that covenants would continue to be struck down on a case-by-case basis, rather than having a bright-line rule.

Benefits: Short, Medium and Long-Term

We should stress that we are presenting possible methods of legal intervention, without expressing a preference as to which of the five options in the menu should be chosen. As lawyers we can say that non-compete clauses inherently raise dignitarian concerns: they restrict workers’ autonomy in the use of their skills, and by obliging them to choose between remaining in workplace environments where they are unhappy, or else leaving the workforce and thus experiencing social exclusion (at least temporarily). We are not in a position to forecast the extent to which changes in the law will promote economic growth, boost existing disappointing productivity levels, and facilitate innovation and entrepreneurship. The composition of the Expert Working Group should reflect the need to bring a broader range of expertise to bear on the choice of regulatory options we have presented. 

Plan of Action

  1. Day One: Secretary of State for Business and Trade convenes a non-statutory Expert Working Group on Labour Market Competition, consisting of economists specialising in labour markets, academic lawyers, and representatives from trade unions, business, and the civil service.

  2. Expert Group is given Terms of Reference: 

    1. to commission and evaluate original research on the prevalence and effect of non-compete covenants in the UK labour market, including on a sectoral basis

    2. lawyers advise on design of regulatory strategies along five distinct parameters:

      1. Ban after a certain time period

      2. Ban above (or below) a certain income level

      3. Mandatory compensation

      4. Industry-specific regulations

      5. Reform of existing legal tests – affording more prominence to the public interest in determining validity

    3. to predict the (positive and negative) effect(s) of each method of regulation, including on a sectoral basis.

  3. Expert Group presents findings to the Secretary of State for Business and Trade, and recommends a regulatory strategy. 

  4. Department for Business and Trade produces a White Paper. 

  5. Public consultation (the last Government’s consultation on this issue was insufficiently rigorous and focused to be taken as determinative).

  6. Legislation introduced to Parliament.

FAQs

How much would your proposal cost? Can you offer a budget estimate? What are the budgetary implications of the actions? 

The costs associated with the operation of the Expert Group, its research and the public consultation are minimal. Determining the costs associated with the various regulatory strategies will be part of the Expert Group’s remit. Previous Government research on this issue indicated the following costs associated with a ban on non-compete covenants for a period longer than three months:

Source: Department of Business and Trade

These primarily consisted of the costs of businesses becoming familiar with the new rules.

Are there any international comparisons or precedents that we can build on? What were the results of these efforts? Why do we think it would work in the UK?

Many jurisdictions regulate non-compete covenants by statute or delegated legislation. The most prominent example of recent reform in this area is the United States of America: in April 2024, the Federal Trade Commission issued a final rule prohibiting the use of non-compete covenants across the US. This harmonised what previously were disparate approaches to regulation across the different states. The justifications cited by the FTC broadly mirror the concerns raised in this paper, albeit with our caveat that we do not know how well the US-based research maps onto the UK labour market, nor the effect on inward investment. At time of writing, it is too early to say whether the effects of the new rule predicted by the FTC have come to pass; moreover, there is uncertainty over the legal validity of the rule.

The European Union does not regulate non-compete covenants directly, but there is well-settled regulation of non-compete covenants in several EU jurisdictions. For example, Germany mandates compensation at 50% of wages, and limits the non-compete covenant to two years. France, like the UK, relies on case-by-case litigation to regulate non-competes, rather than statute; financial compensation is required during the period of the covenant. One of the present authors has argued elsewhere for convergence between the approach of the common law in England and Wales to non-compete covenants with methods used in EU competition law for addressing anti-competitive behaviour by businesses.

The Australian federal government is currently considering regulation of non-compete covenants. Its consultation process has recently closed.

What are past or ongoing efforts that are related to your proposed actions? 

Non-compete covenants in employment contracts have been regulated by the common law (ie judge-made law) of restraint of trade since at least the 15th century. The common law rules provide that the covenant must be no greater than is reasonably necessary for the purposes of enabling the employer to protect its trade secrets or customer base. If the protection afforded to the employer by the covenant goes beyond this standard, the courts will strike it down as unenforceable. 

In determining whether the standard has been satisfied, the courts consider the length of the covenant, e.g. a period of six months may be valid, but a twelve-month prohibition will often be held to be a restraint of trade and unenforceable. The courts also consider the extent of the geographical restriction, the scope of the market or business of the employer, whether the employer would be sufficiently protected by a ‘garden leave’ clause (ie, a provision in the employment contract that compels an employee not to work and to stay away from the employer’s place of work during the notice period where the employee has served notice on the employer that they intend to leave employment) and the nature of the competitive activities that the employee is prevented or restricted from carrying out post-termination. In a recent decision of the UK Supreme Court (Tillman v Egon Zehnder), the Court ruled that if part of the wording of the non-compete covenant can be removed to make the rest of the covenant enforceable, they will be prepared to use their ‘blue pencil’ to ‘sever’ the impugned section of text.

In recent years, the UK Government has considered reforming the law. For example, in May 2016, it issued a ‘Call for Evidence’ to explore the legitimacy of non-compete covenants, seeking the views of consultees on the proposition that they stifled British entrepreneurship by preventing workers from moving freely between employers, developing new innovative ideas, translating those ideas into a start-up, and growing their own businesses after leaving a job. 

After the UK Government’s Call for Evidence, there was a period of hiatus for around five years, but in February 2021, it released a consultation paper presenting two reform options: first, that employers pay mandatory compensation to employees during any period they are restrained by a non-compete covenant; and secondly, that non-compete covenants be banned, either completely, or after a particular period of time. In May 2023, the UK Government announced that it would legislate to ban non-compete covenants that lasted for a period of three months or more. Non-compete clauses that were for a period of less than three months would continue to be regulated by the common law. 

What government agency, department, or body will lead this effort? 

The effort will be led by the Department for Business and Trade, with the support of a newly-appointed Expert Working Group on Labour Market Competition.

Who are important stakeholders, and who might help champion or advocate for your proposal?

The most important stakeholders are employee representatives (trade unions) and businesses, particularly in the sectors of Business Services, Finance and Insurance, and Information and Communication, where non-compete covenants are most common. 

We expect trade unions and representatives of start-up and small businesses to champion the proposal.

How might your proposed action fit in within the broader priorities of the government or relative departments? 

Subject to new economic research confirming that restrictions on non-competes would improve productivity and innovation and increase wages, these are all clearly in keeping with longstanding UK Government policy. As for empowering workers: existing legislative policy favours individual labour mobility over collective representation as a means for workers to achieve better outcomes – ie, current UK law prefers ‘exit’ to ‘voice’. Curtailing non-competes allows workers to ‘vote with their feet’, and is therefore a means of boosting worker power distinct from, and complementary to, improving the legal rights of trade unions.

Can your proposal be undertaken with existing department authorities and funding or is legislative action needed?

Legislation will be needed for all five options proposed above. Even reform of the common law public interest test, to reshape the factors taken into account and weight these are given, would be most easily accomplished through legislation. Option (i) would involve primary legislation prohibiting non-compete covenants outside designated income limits; it would be best for these limits to be set by secondary legislation so they can be adjusted in accordance with inflation and other Government policy decisions. Option (iv) would involve primary legislation empowering the Secretary of State to specify which rules applied to which industries, again by means of secondary legislation.

Who might resist such a proposal?

Some employers in particular business sectors, such as finance, technology, professional services, business services, insurance, AI, etc may object to the proposals on the basis that their inability to restrain key staff from exiting immediately will deter them from investing in staff training and R&D on the basis that they cannot be certain that they will not lose key data, IP, know-how, skills and trade secrets that they have developed. This concern, however, could be overcome if the Expert Working Group’s research indicates that the economic benefits of curtailments on a ban on non-competes outweigh the costs associated with the proposal.

What accountability and evaluation measures are going to be included to ensure that the proposal is carried out well?

The most efficient way to ensure accountability and evaluation is to maintain the proposed Expert Working Group, to commission longitudinal research of the effect on labour market mobility, wages and economic productivity attributable to the implementation of the chosen regulation.

What similar activity is already happening in this space? Are your proposals distinct or complementary? Why are existing efforts insufficient?

As recited above, the UK Government has consulted on proposals in this area in 2016 and 2021-22, and the CMA produced a report in 2024. In 2023, the last Government proposed a time-based ban on non-compete covenants, having rejected the option of mandatory compensation. Its proposal was not implemented before the 2024 election. We are concerned that the evidence base available to the Department for Business and Trade when making this proposal was insufficient, and that some potential regulatory responses have not been adequately considered.

David Cabrelli

David Cabrelli

David Cabrelli is Professor of Labour Law at the University of Edinburgh. His research on employment and labour law has been cited by the UK Supreme Court, the Hong Kong High Court and the Federal Court of Australia, as well as the Law Commission, the Scottish Law Commission, the House of Commons Library and the ILO. 

Alan Eustace

Alan Eustace

Alan Eustace is Assistant Professor of Private Law, Trinity College Dublin and formerly Fellow of Magdalen College, University of Oxford. His research focuses on trade union law and workers’ civil liberties, and has been cited in the Irish Parliament.

Contact Us

For more information about our initiative, partnerships, or support, get in touch with us at hello@ukdayone.org

Submit an idea

Socials

UKDayOne

Contact Us

For more information about our initiative, partnerships, or support, get in touch with us at hello@ukdayone.org

Submit an idea

Socials

Contact Us

For more information about our initiative, partnerships, or support, get in touch with us at hello@ukdayone.org

Submit an idea

Socials

Introduction
briefings
about
learn more
Introduction
briefings
about
learn more